The Division of and Specialization of Labor

The formal study of economics began when Adam Smith (17231790) published his famous book The Wealth of Nations in 1776. Many authors had written on economics in the centuries before Smith, but he was the first to address the subject in a comprehensive way. In the first chapter, Smith introduces the division of labor, which means that the way a good or service is produced is divided into a number of tasks that are performed by different workers, instead of all the tasks being done by the same person.

AWL: economics!
AWL: published!
AWL: authors!
AWL: economics!
AWL: comprehensive!
AWL: chapter!
AWL: labor!
AWL: tasks!
AWL: tasks!

To illustrate the division of labor, Smith counted how many tasks went into making a pin: drawing out a piece of wire, cutting it to the right length, straightening it, putting a head on one end and a point on the other, and packaging pins for sale, to name just a few. Smith counted 18 distinct tasks that were often done by different peopleall for a pin, believe it or not!

AWL: illustrate!
AWL: labor!
AWL: tasks!
AWL: distinct!
AWL: tasks!

Modern businesses divide tasks as well. Even a relatively simple business like a restaurant divides up the task of serving meals into a range of jobs like top chef, sous chefs, less-skilled kitchen help, servers to wait on the tables, a greeter at the door, janitors to clean up, and a business manager to handle paychecks and billsnot to mention the economic connections a restaurant has with suppliers of food, furniture, kitchen equipment, and the building where it is located. A complex business like a large manufacturing factory, such as the shoe factory or a hospital can have hundreds of job classifications.

AWL: tasks!
AWL: task!
AWL: range!
AWL: jobs!
AWL: economic!
AWL: equipment!
AWL: located!
AWL: complex!
AWL: job!

When the tasks involved with producing a good or service are divided and subdivided, workers and businesses can produce a greater quantity of output. In his observations of pin factories, Smith observed that one worker alone might make 20 pins in a day, but that a small business of 10 workers (some of whom would need to do two or three of the 18 tasks involved with pin-making), could make 48,000 pins in a day. How can a group of workers, each specializing in certain tasks, produce so much more than the same number of workers who try to produce the entire good or service by themselves? Smith offered three reasons.

AWL: tasks!
AWL: involved!
AWL: output!
AWL: tasks!
AWL: involved!
AWL: tasks!

First, specialization in a particular small job allows workers to focus on the parts of the production process where they have an advantage. People have different skills, talents, and interests, so they will be better at some jobs than at others. The particular advantages may be based on educational choices, which are in turn shaped by interests and talents. Only those with medical degrees qualify to become doctors, for instance. For some goods, specialization will be affected by geographyit is easier to be a wheat farmer in North Dakota than in Florida, but easier to run a tourist hotel in Florida than in North Dakota. If you live in or near a big city, it is easier to attract enough customers to operate a successful dry cleaning business or movie theater than if you live in a sparsely populated rural area. Whatever the reason, if people specialize in the production of what they do best, they will be more productive than if they produce a combination of things, some of which they are good at and some of which they are not.

AWL: job!
AWL: focus!
AWL: process!
AWL: jobs!
AWL: medical!
AWL: instance!
AWL: affected!
AWL: area!

Second, workers who specialize in certain tasks often learn to produce more quickly and with higher quality. This pattern holds true for many workers, including assembly line laborers who build cars, stylists who cut hair, and doctors who perform heart surgery. In fact, specialized workers often know their jobs well enough to suggest innovative ways to do their work faster and better.

AWL: tasks!
AWL: assembly!
AWL: jobs!
AWL: innovative!

A similar pattern often operates within businesses. In many cases, a business that focuses on one or a few products is more successful than firms that try to make a wide range of products.

AWL: similar!
AWL: focuses!
AWL: range!

Third, specialization allows businesses to take advantage of economies of scale, which means that for many goods, as the level of production increases, the average cost of producing each individual unit declines. For example, if a factory produces only 100 cars per year, each car will be quite expensive to make on average. However, if a factory produces 50,000 cars each year, then it can set up an assembly line with huge machines and workers performing specialized tasks, and the average cost of production per car will be lower. The ultimate result of workers who can focus on their preferences and talents, learn to do their specialized jobs better, and work in larger organizations is that society as a whole can produce and consume far more than if each person tried to produce all of their own goods and services. The division and specialization of labor has been a force against the problem of scarcity.

AWL: economies!
AWL: individual!
AWL: declines!
AWL: assembly!
AWL: tasks!
AWL: ultimate!
AWL: focus!
AWL: jobs!
AWL: consume!
AWL: labor!

Citation

OpenStax College, Principles of Economics. OpenStax College.19 March 2014. Retrieved from http://cnx.org/content/col11613/latest/ on 03 Oct 2016. (link). Adapted and reproduced here under a CC BY 3.0 license.